Down With Proposition 12

The Supreme Court of the United States (SCOTUS) recently affirmed that the measures in  Proposition 12 (in National Pork Producers Council v. Ross) do not violate the “Dormant Commerce Clause” because the complaining parties did not prove how the law discriminates against out-of-state producers when it equally applied to those situated in California. The voters of California passed Proposition 12 in 2018, amended Chapter 10, Article 3 of the California Code of Regulations, imposing more stringent standards for the breeding of pigs (Section 1322.1(a). All because the plaintiffs made faulty legal arguments does not mean the law is economically sound.

Most animal cruelty laws focus on the emotions of voters; people deplore animal mistreatment. The “humane pork law” might elicit emotional responses, but there numerous drawbacks. Other states may consider passing similar measures and suffer from the adverse downstream consequences. These regulations artificially restricting the meat supply raise prices but cannot guarantee animal welfare. The free market, rather than top-down laws, can better accommodate the preferences of consumers who demand ethical meat.

Vote with Your Wallet, Not the Ballot Box!

One of the best mechanisms for ensuring food safety and humane treatment of livestock would be feedback in sales. If firms continue to sell large quantities of pork raised in inhumane conditions, producers can assume that consumers are not worried by the breeding conditions of pigs. Among California voters and pork consumers, there is a disconnect between their purchasing decisions and the pork products available. If these individuals were concerned about pigs, they would stop buying pork products. The use of government fiat to remedy this issue ignores that producers respond to what customers buy. If pork sales plummet, prudent companies will work to alleviate the concerns regarding the sanitation and safety of commercial slaughterhouses and breeding facilities. In contrast, if consumers remain lackadaisical about the issue and continue to buy bacon from “unethical” processing facilities, what incentive do procedures have to change their ways?

Voters/consumers relying on government remedies to make the food supply safer and more ethical is an example of moral hazard. Moral hazard is the phenomenon where “..people tend to take more risks when they do not bear the full potential negative consequence.. “. When voters defer the issue to the state legislature, this is only passing the buck. If producers took a hit on their bottom line, being profit-oriented, they would respond by improving the living conditions for their livestock. It is easier to continue to purchase pork chops every week and wait for the referendum; versus organizing a boycott or voicing your concerns in a letter to pork producers expressing your concerns. Animal welfare proponents can even adopt a vegan lifestyle if they believe pork slaughter practices are unsafe and immoral. Shoppers can also purchase substitute goods (the demand for pork is relatively elastic). The above solutions do not interfere with the rights of producers or apathetic bacon eaters.

However, there are already private means to reinforce humane slaughter practices for animals bred for commercial meat. If meat eaters demand “humane” pork it is in the best interest of producers to satisfy this consumer preference. Ethical pork processors like Beeler’s Pure Pork have branded themselves as offering humane pork products. The company’s website describes facilities that are not only spacious and hygienic. Even providing pigs with adequate shelter from inclement weather. These amenities for their livestock are an attempt to meet the demands of the niche ethical meat market; without the coercive force of municipal, state, and federal laws. Individual firms taking matters into their own are not the only private measures that can enforce ethical slaughter practices. Apolitical third-party organizations can examine and certify living conditions and slaughter practices, a fine example is the program implemented by American Humane.

This Amendment Increases the Price of Pork

The animal welfare interest of Section 1322.1(a) may viscerally tug at our heartstrings, but it overshadows one of the central concerns of consumer welfare; prices! The provisions in Proposition 12, directly and indirectly, increase the price of pork sold in California. The spike in pork prices is not the result of market demand for pork chops but the costs of compliance with the law. Since the law requires larger enclosures for living and husbandry, pig farmers will need more land or materials to accommodate the conditions specified in Section 1322.1(a). Since pig farmers do not raise pigs out of “..benevolence..”, but for profit, they must pass these costs along to the consumer to stay afloat financially.

Indirectly, this measure raises prices by implementing onerous requirements that reduce the number of vendors willing to sell and process pork products in California. The  Law of Supply and Demand applies here because legally restricting the number of qualified producers will decrease the pork supply and increase the supply (providing the demand remains constant). Pork prices will level off once the few complying firms can meet current pork demand (or if demand for pork slumps). In-state farmers might choose to close shop, but the most devasting impact will come from the out-of-state producers choosing the California market. It is estimated that 87 % of “…pork sold in California comes from pigs raised outside the state..”. While consumers can boycott goods, suppliers can deny service in protest. A lesson currently being learned in Florida (Truckers refusing to service Florida due to new immigration laws). Pork producers could refuse to sell their products in California to protest the new animal welfare regulations.

Regulations Cannot Guarantee Animal Welfare

California is projected to experience a “..$320M economic loss..” from the animal welfare initiative. This is a hefty price tag considering these measures cannot guarantee that this improves the safety and sanitation of pigs bred for consumption. It is nearly impossible to promulgate airtight laws with no loopholes. Nor can any public policy measure anticipate every possible environmental threat to the well-being of pigs raised for pork. One blindspot in the regulation highlighted by pig farmers is that the initiative never accounted for the harm caused by pig-on-pig aggression, an issue easily remedied by confinement measures prohibited under Section 1322.1(a).

 This is because laws, like all forms of government action, suffer from the “pretense of knowledge”, a concept formulated by Nobel Laureate; F.A. Hayek. Since information is dispersed and is ..not concentrated in any single individuals or institutions..”, regulation is a top-down approach that is too lethargic and inflexible in addressing consumer preferences. It is best to let individual firms tailor their slaughter and meat processing practices to the needs of their customers instead of a one-size-fits-all rule.

 The National Pork Producers Decision Avoids Lochner

Photo by Leah Kelley on Pexels.com

In National Pork Producers Council v. Ross the Supreme Court ruled that the amendments to Chapter 10, Article 3 of the California Code of Regulations through the referendum Proposition 12 (California, 2018) were constitutional. The high court found that provisions amending the California code did not violate the “Dormant Commerce Clause”.  Blackman and Barnett details:

“..Whatever one thinks about these critiques, we do not need to engage with any of them to resolve this case. Even under our received dormant Commerce Clause case law, petitioners begin in a tough spot. They do not allege that California’s law seeks to advantage in-state firms or disadvantage out-of-state rivals. Petitioners disavow any discrimination-based claim, conceding that Proposition 12 imposes the same burdens on in-state pork producers that it imposes on out-of-state ones. As petitioners put it, “the dormant Commerce Clause . . . bar on protectionist state statutes that discriminate against interstate commerce . . . is not an issue here. (p.3)..”

Since the law equally applies to in-state and out-of-state pork producers, it does not violate the Dormant Commerce Clause. This does not mean that the law is free of economic fallacies. What is legal is not always economically sound!

Despite all the flaws of the regulations promulgated from Proposition 12, the court might have acknowledged its institutional limits. Saving us from committing the same error of the Lochner Decision (Lochner v. New York), colloquially known as the “Bake Shop Case”. The Progressive Era believed that they were defending economic freedom by upholding freedom of contract under the Fourteenth Amendment (the Ninth Amendment might have been a better fit for protecting this unenumerated right). Lochner has been universally (p.374) criticized by both liberal and conservative jurists, so why was this decision so deplorable? The verdict undermines the “police power” of the states to make laws regulating health and safety. This enables the court to interfere with this authority and blurs the line between interpreting the law and backdoor rule-making. The Bake Shop Act (1895) was idiotic, but the court was overstepping by invoking the Fourteenth Amendment to justify striking down the maximum hours rule.

The “Humane Pork Law” mimics the Bake Shop Act, both laws; are deeply misguided from the standpoint of liberty and economic efficiency. The SCOTUS had another opportunity to overextend its authority but exercised constraint. The Pork Law is nothing to celebrate, but we should all celebrate that it did not get struck down. We may have avoided a baby Lochner decision!

Friday Feature Film-A Food Safety Double Feature- Frontline: Modern Meat (PBS, 2002) & The Meat Lobby: How the Meat Industry Hides the Truth (ENDEVR)

Yes, the Frontline episode is dated, but contamination by foodborne pathogens is still a concern in our food supply. The question becomes who has the true lobbying power. Big meat or the media?

Superficially most people would assume the Big Meat Packers. Along with a litany of think tanks and lobbyist organizations ( North American Meat Institute) bending statistics to justify deregulation or keeping the status quo.

What is more intriguing are the interest groups that make up the pro-regulation coalition. The news media not only prospers from gaining more readers and viewers, but these organizations also reduce the informational costs of political action. Media outlets bring attention to public policy issues elevating the topic to a focal point. Individuals typically unaware of a specific problem become mobilized and more apt to seek other like-minded individuals to unify their political pursuits. In the 1990s, following the Jack-In-The-Box E.coli outbreak and several other incidences, there was a greater demand for more food regulation. Some of the literature refers to this knee-jerk reaction as “Pavlovian politics”. The meat lobby may have deep pockets, but the fear-mongering of the 24-hour news cycle provides stiff competition.

The Outer Limits of Woke Corporate Rent-Seeking (Bud Light & Jack Daniels)

Photo by Mustata Silva on Pexels.com

The recent blowback from consumers against Bud Light and Jack Daniels over their pro-LGBTQ+ partnerships illustrates more than just the contentions of the current culture war in the United States. Both incidents are clear demarcations of the limits of woke corporate rent-seeking. There is a clear difference from the standpoint of leverage when a firm is either on the supply side; or the demand side of the supply curve.

(Courtesy of Wikimedia)

On the demand side, firms have much more influence over woke policies as they are the customers in this scenario. When a company employs a worker, they effectively purchase their skills and services, placing them on the demand side of the supply curve. As the consumer, the firm has significantly more latitude to expect; the prospective employee will tolerate politically correct messaging. This validates the Strategic Depth Theory of Diversity and Inclusion. Because of the strong incentives of firms to avoid litigation and the fact they purchase the labor of employees, the employees have to tolerate politically correct or woke corporate initiatives or otherwise find alternative means of employment.

However, while watching Kid Rock blast through a case of Bud Light with an AR-15 is entertaining political theater, it conveys a deeper truism about the market. Customers always have the ultimate leverage in the market! What these corporations have lost sight of when they do not have purchasing power on the supply side to ideologically virtue signal; they are the individuals that need to cater to the preferences of others. The tone-deaf appeals to the LGBTQ+ community by both Inbev (owner of Bud Light) and Brown-Forman (owner of Jack Daniels) neglect the needs of their loyal customer base. There is ample evidence that both brands have customer bases that leaned toward political conservativism. The attempt to appeal to the left-wing sensibilities of Gen-Z may have been a waste, considering they are less likely to be drinkers. Let alone prefer more macho and alcohol-forward brands like Budweiser or Jack Daniels.

(Courtesy of Washington Post)

However, for Inbev, it might be more an exercise in optics than it is about expanding market share (most likely the objective of Brown-Forman). Inbev is attempting to recover from the “Pride Month incident” of 2021. What better way to quell the concerns of the transgender community than to partner with Dylan Mulvaney? If most Bud Light consumers were liberals, then it would be a fine idea. But when your customers are blue-collar workers and country music fans, you might want to lean more into your support for right-wing politicians

The Paradox of Centralized Regulatory Review

Photo by Ethan Wilkinson on Pexels.com

One counteractive observation made in the paper A Note on the centralized regulatory review (1984) is to centralize the review of regulation; to a single government bureau. Most libertarians would take issue with consolidating political power into one entity. However, as Miller, Shughart, and Tollison, explains centralization may benefit the private interests that oppose the implementation of the regulation. As befuddling as this suggestion may seem, this impacts the transaction costs of opposing government action.  

“…In contrast, centralized oversight enables diffuse interests to focus their lobbying against rent-creating regulation on one location rather than splitting those efforts among a variety of regulatory agencies. In effect, centralization sums the individual welfare losses created by the regulatory bodies subject to its jurisdiction. When one considers the prevalence of regulatory intervention in the economy, the overall cost to diffuse is likely to be quite substantial. Summing the individual welfare losses from rulemaking activities that create rents raises the rate of return to lobbying against such regulation. Accordingly, more opposition will be forthcoming. (p.86-87)..”

While this may incur more costs for the lobbyist who pray upon the concept of “…concentrated benefits and dispersed costs..”, reciprocally, this would reduce the costs for private parties (grassroots coalitions of average citizens) looking to defeat the pending legislation.

“…In consequence, centralization will result in more speeches being made against rent- creating rulemaking, more articles written on the subject of regulatory reform, more letters and telephone calls to Congress from concerned consumers, more campaign contributions to politicians advocating deregulation in the economic area (and more and improved regulation in the social area), more consumer lobbying groups being formed, and so forth. The argument we have presented applies to any situation in which rent-seeking opportunities exist within a decentralized administrative framework. Centralization alters the relative rates of return to lobbying for various coalitions, generally in favor of groups having diffuse interests…” (p.87).

The “…diffused interests…” referred to by Miller, Shughart, and Tollison would be the coalitions of regular voters. Potentially, rallying against divisive “wedge issues” such as the Second Amendment or Abortion. Usually, grassroots political movements will not have the capital to petition multiple bureaus the way entrenched interest groups (lobbyists) influence government action. The centralization may seem like an institutional drive to expand the scope of government, but it may have the opposite effect on lobbying. Realigning the incentives of grassroots activities by reducing the costs of devoting resources towards political action.

Tullock, Transitional Gains Trap, & Barriers to Entry

Gordon Tullock’s, paper The Transitional Gains Trap (1975) reveals some counterintuitive insights into government programs. Most Libertarians, Classical Liberals, and some Conservatives would surmise that one of the reasons why government programs have prolonged longevity is that the “..entrenched interests..” continue to gain from the policy. However, much like any other entrepreneurial endeavor, the early entrants reap the rewards of the government initiative (think of the consequences of creative destruction). Tullock concludes that individuals that hop on the bandwagon later fare about as well as they would have in the private sector.

The clearest example Tullock articulates in this paper is the example of civil service examinations. Why? Generally, public sector jobs provide higher compensation than their private sector counterparts (p.675). The higher wages would attract more job candidates requiring hiring managers within government bureaus to devise more rigorous validation methods for selecting competent employees. But considering how extensive the test is (including many difficult questions that have little pertinence to the job), effectively, the successful candidates would be overqualified. (p.676). Per Tullock:

“…As a result, the employees are overqualified for the job itself, although not for the examination. In equilibrium, individuals choosing to take a civil service job would expect about the same discounted lifetime earnings as if they had taken a job in private industry which had an inherent requirement for higher quality labor than in the civil service job. There is a significant social cost in the sense that the jobs are held by people whose native capacity is such that they could hold better jobs equally well. For example, the private post offices that are now so successfully competing with the government Postal Service, in those areas where they are legal, normally hire much lower quality labor and pay a much lower wage than the Postal Service. It should be emphasized that, although this is true, they also get much more work from their employees. A custom of working only part of the day has developed in the Postal Service, and many letter carriers are done with their day’s work in much less than an eight-hour stint..” (p.676).

Tullock also likens this to the job stability of trade union members, senior union members capitalize on the initial benefits, and the public sector market of jobs stabilizes the returns even out and ends up being no better than the private sector (p. 675). This paper also mentions how policies that favor specific industries (notably unions and public sector jobs) would yield more direct benefits from pure transfers. Such a privilege is direct monetary allocation versus the implementation of disparate rules that favor the economic success of a specific sector in the American economy. The best example of this cited by Tullock is agricultural subsidies (p. 676) which directly distribute money to farmers rather than enacting laws making it more onerous to become a farmer. One of the most salient examples is the subsidies provided for a farmer for cultivating corn.

The irony of a transition strategy (creating barriers to entry versus direct handouts) is that it is less efficient. The question has become, why would political actors choose the more circuitous and less profitable route? Tullock being the exquisite scholar he was, provides several explanations for this perplexing phenomenon. As we all know, prima facie, the political process makes everything more complex, and that even goes for the interest groups attempting to game the system. Essentially, erecting legislative barriers may be less lucrative, but are easier to pass through because not to incite the ire of voters (being more subtle than a direct handout); such measures side-step annual budgetary reviews of congress and are scrutinized at less frequent intervals than earmarked subsidies (p.677).  

There is much we can do about the existing measures that favor select industries; one only needs to look at the Public Choice literature on inertia to understand that the status quo reigns supreme. Even outside of the Public Choice tradition, free-market economists have long acknowledged this truism of government intervention. Nobel-prize winner Milton Friedman summed it up best by stating “… Nothing is so permanent as a temporary government program..”. The only wisdom Tullock imparts upon us to prevent the Transitional Gains Trap is “..I can recommend very strongly that we try to avoid getting into such traps in the future..” (p.678). His response nearly fifty years ago illustrates the futility of attempting to prevent interest groups from influencing public policy.

Against AB-418 (California, 2023): Taste The Rainbow

In February, the California legislature introduced Assembly Bill No. 418 (AB-418), legislation that seeks to expand the state Health and Safety Code. The amendment would ban the sale and production of edible goods containing Brominated vegetable oil, Potassium bromate, Propylparaben, Red dye 3, and Titanium dioxide; by January 2025.

This bill has gained national attention for prohibiting one of the constituents (Titanium Dioxide) in the popular candy, Skittles. Mars’s use of the ingredient sparked controversy last year. In Thames v. Mars, Inc, the U.S. District Court of Northern California dismissed the complaint. Mars claimed they would stop using Titanium Dioxide in their Skittles candies in 2016. The proposed consumer protection measure is likely a response to candy manufacturers not following through on their publicized commitment.

AB-418, like all consumer protection legislation, is well-intentioned but misguided. Prohibiting certain chemicals in food products is unnecessary when market mechanisms can guide producers accordingly. If consumers are concerned about the hazards of ingesting compounds targeted in the bill, they will choose not to purchase these products. In turn, companies like Mars will respond accordingly to market pressures.

Consumer Sovereignty Can Lead the Way

Consumer Sovereignty is the concept that “…consumer preferences determine the production of goods and services..”; any competitive firm will be responsive to the needs and wants of its customers. If candy consumers are truly troubled by Skittles containing Titanium Dioxide, they will stop purchasing Skittles (other brands impacted by AB-418). Mars will then respond to the dip in sales by accommodating the preferences of their customer base by removing this substance from their products. If consumers are still buying Skittles, we can assume that they are not bothered by the fact, Skittles contains this chemical. Therefore, the implementation of a law banning this ingredient is unnecessary.

But beyond such a law is unnecessary, it also infringes upon the right to choose. An individual should be able to purchase and eat any variety of candy they so wish, even if it is injurious to their health. California’s prospective law could ruin the skittles recipe and impact the flavor. Why should companies manufacturing processed foods be forced to meet such requirements if most consumers are indifferent to these health concerns?

Product Differentiation Can Voluntarily Steer Consumers 

Product differentiation is where a firm highlights the attributes of its products or services that set them apart from its competitors. Mars’s failure to fulfill its 2016 commitment is not a reason for more regulation; but a golden opportunity for competing companies to acquire more business. Competitors can either emphasize in their branding that they do not use Titanium Dioxide or voluntarily reformulate their products. Firms placing such a focus on product quality will provide a signal to health-conscious customers; such tactics can persuade candy consumers to switch brands.

The process of product differentiation can also present an opportunity for mainstream candy companies to create multitiered product lines. They may have products containing the same artificial ingredients that compose the Skittles recipe but also offer an ultra-premium line of candies made with more natural ingredients. Such an offering accommodates concerned customers by providing a “healthier” alternative to the original mass-market product, creating a niche market for consumers willing to pay more for quality.  

Government Intervention Will Only Lead to Moral Hazard

The state of California banning specific food additives will give the producers and consumers the impression that the ultimate responsibility of ensuring safety will be on the government. This perception can create perverse incentives for firms and customers alike. 

This situation will generate what is known as a moral hazard. Moral hazard is the phenomenon where “..people tend to take more risks when they do not bear the full potential negative consequence..”. Since the government took full responsibility for determining what substances are safe to consume in food products, both parties are willing to take more risks.   Producers will be little incentive to provide above-average safety quality with their edible products because California will be the ultimate authority making this determination. Because government safety standards only provide minimum standards, they will only meet the bare minimum. Firms may hold higher safety and cleanliness standards when subject to profits guided by consumer preferences. Why? Because companies may want to increase customer loyalty by aiming to exceed their current food safety expectations. In contrast, the minimum mandated criteria imposed by California, firms will have no reason to adopt more stringent standards because there is no profit incentive to exceed government standards. Consumers will credulously accept the lackluster effort on the part of candy producers simply because they have the government seal of approval. 

The government prohibiting certain food additives also generates moral hazards for consumers. If the government parentally informs you what substances are safe through legal restrictions, why do you need to do any additional research? Many people believe that products are wholesome because they are legal. But do local, state, and federal government base these determinations on sound medical research? Not always. Health and safety legislation, like other policies, can be subject to the influence of various interest groups hoping to shape regulations to their advantage (regulatory capture). One analogous example is the labeling requirements for genetically modified food because these mandates have little scientific justification. Yet, these requirements continue to be aggressively supported by coalitions that stand to gain from this regulation.

Bootleggers & Baptists LXVII- California Banning Skittles (Taste the Rainbow)

The case Thames v. Mars, Inc (2022) filed in the district court of Northern California, brought to light safety concerns regarding the ingredients of the popular candy, Skittles. Thames alleged that the fruit-flavored candies contained “..contain titanium dioxide (‘TiO2’), a known toxin..” which Mars claimed they would phase out of using in their products back in 2016. The plaintiff listed several California consumer protection measures justifying their suit against the candy maker. But in the end, the plaintiff voluntarily dismissed his claim against the company.

However, the concerns of Thames have not been ignored by the state of California. As the state legislature proposes AB-418 (2023-2024), which seeks to amend “SECTION 1. Chapter 17 (commencing with Section 109025) is added to Part 3 of Division 104 of the Health and Safety Code, CHAPTER 

17. Food Safety to ban the use of Titanium dioxide in food products by January 2025. But keeping the Bootlegger and Baptists (1983), who benefits from banning Titanium dioxide as an ingredient of edible merchandise?

The company under fire (Mars) is the true beneficiary of the soon-to-be California law. Why? A company like Mars (arguably the largest candy company in the world) has the resources to accommodate the regulatory requirements imposed by California lawmakers. Mars can (at little cost to their profits) substitute Titanium dioxide for a legal ingredient. But smaller candy producers may not be flexible and will go out of business due to these new requirements. Therefore, Mars a silent Bootlegger in this scenario.

Bootleggers & Baptists: LXVI- DeSantis, Liquor Licenses, & Christmas Drag Shows

Florida Governor Ron DeSantis of Florida has recently drummed up some controversy last week when he revoked the liquor license of Hyatt Regency Miami for hosting a Christmas drag show displaying sexually explicit performances. So, what was the controversy? Not all of the attendees, were over the age of 18 (per the State Florida Department of Business and Professional Regulation complaint). [1]. The DeSantis administration in Florida has expressed normative concern about insulating children from “lewd” content. Per the State of Florida’s grievance:

“…As a result, minors attended and were knowingly admitted into the Show by Respondent, including children appearing less than 16 years of age. See Exhibit 5. 9. During the Show and in the presence of persons less than 16 years of age, performers appeared on stage wearing sexually suggestive clothing and prosthetic female genitalia…”

However, viewing this situation through the prism of Bruce Yandle’s Bootleggers and Baptists (1983) framework, who benefits from this decision? Anyone familiar with the city of Miami knows that the city has no shortage of bars and restaurants licensed to serve alcoholic beverages. While DeSantis and those working for the state of Florida may be our Baptists; it is evident that bars throughout Miami are the Bootleggers of the Hyatt having its liquor license pulled. Why? Because alcohol sales equal more revenue and business. Some patrons might even avoid venues that do not serve alcohol. Other local venues stand to profit handsomely from the loss in the competition since alcohol has the highest markup of any item on a restaurant or bar’s menu.

Notes:

1.) We cannot rule out the possibility of partisanship in this policy decision. It is not evident that if a father brought his 16-year-old son to a female strip club (colloquially known as a “Titty Bar”) DeSantis would have reacted with the same amount of gusto. However, considering the implicit partisanship of the American “culture war” it would be fair to suggest that California Governor Newsom would more harshly penalize the “Titty Bar” over the Drag Show. The inequitable application of the law based on the ideological leanings of elected officials is an unfortunate excess of the current American political climate.

Why Liberalism is Worth Pursuing

Photo by Quang Anh Ha Nguyen on Pexels.com

Liberalism has not failed but has never been fully pursued in public policy. True liberalism, classical liberalism, is the Lockean philosophy that protects natural individualistic rights or negative rights from the authoritarian restrictions of government fiat. But in contrast to the current perversion of liberalism in the form of Progressive ideology that seeks to expand the breadth of state authority purportedly in the name of equality. The regulations we assume are legitimate conflict with true liberalism by giving the state more power to interfere with private affairs. Sincere liberalism protects private property rights, individual liberty, and economic liberty from the coercive tentacles of state intrusion, even if these measures yield equitable results. It may be reasonable to assume liberalism has failed when filtered through the prism of Progressive thought, but this is not true liberalism. Actual liberalism allows individuals to pursue their happiness without the restrictions imposed by contemporary liberalism.

Bootleggers & Baptists: LXV- Randy McNally, TN LGBTQ Laws, & Political Optics

Trafalgar Square – gay rights protest by Chris Allen is licensed under CC-BY-SA 2.0

The current controversy surrounding Tennessee Lt. governor Randall McNally is a boon to the Left-wingers in this political climate amid America’s “Culture War”. He has tacitly supported several laws that the Human Rights Campaign believes targets the LGBTQ+ community [1]. Notably, SB0003 (2023) which places restrictions on drag performances, has been a hotly debated topic on editorial pages coast to coast. Why has McNally’s stance on Anti-LGBTQ+ legislation recently come under fire? McNally has recently interacted with a gay social media figure liking several sexually provocative posts, creating a gap between his political positions and his personal opinions. The TN Lt. Governor has expressed; that his replies were misinterpreted and did repudiate the perception that he was anti-LGBTQ, but never stated that he wasn’t a homosexual [2].

In the context of Bruce Yandle’s Bootleggers and Baptists (1983) framework, who benefits from these laws regulating sexuality and gender? We don’t need to look too far to see who the Baptists are, clearly the Conservative (most likely religious) lawmakers, because they are enacting these laws in the name of morality and the wellbeing of the youth. McNally himself is probably the most salient beneficiary of these laws. Why? Since he either sympathizes with the LGBTQ community or is a closeted member, he can easily refute any association with this enclave of sexual minorities within the state by pointing (free-riding) to the laws he implicitly endorsed. The optics of McNally not appearing to be openly pro-LGBTQ is imperative in a staunchly conservative state like Tennessee. If his open support is off-putting to state voters, he might as well kiss his cushy seat in the state house goodbye.  

Notes:

  1. This essay is merely an application of Bruce Yandle’s coalition model and is not a commentary on Tennessee state laws, McNally, or the LGBTQ+ community.
  2. Interesting observation, but speculating about the nature of McNally’s sexual orientation is slightly outside the bounds of my analysis.